Pigovian Tax: Definition, Purpose, Calculation, and Examples

What Is a Pigovian Tax?

A Pigovian (also spelled Pigouvian) tax is a tax assessed against businesses and private individuals that engage in activities that create adverse side effects for society. Those can include environmental pollution, strains on public healthcare systems from the sale of tobacco products, or any other side effects that have an external, negative impact.

Pigovian taxes were named after English economist Arthur Pigou, a significant contributor to early externality theory. Pigou also promoted the link between the balance of consumption, employment, and price, known as the Pigou effect.

Key Takeaways

  • A Pigovian tax is intended to make the producer of goods or services that create adverse side effects for society cover that cost.
  • Economists argue that the costs of these "negative externalities," such as environmental pollution, are otherwise borne by society rather than the producer.
  • A carbon emissions tax or a tax on plastic bags are examples of Pigovian taxes.
  • Pigovian taxes are meant to equal the cost of the negative externality, although that can be difficult to determine and, if overestimated, can potentially harm society.

Understanding a Pigovian Tax

A Pigovian tax is meant to discourage activities that impose a cost of production onto third parties and society as a whole. According to Pigou, these negative externalities prevent a market economy from reaching equilibrium when producers do not take on all costs of production. This adverse effect might be corrected, he suggested, by levying taxes equal to the externalized costs. Ideally, the tax would also give the producer an incentive to reduce the negative externalities they are responsible for.

Negative externalities are not necessarily "bad." Instead, a negative externality occurs whenever an economic entity does not fully internalize the costs of its activity. In these situations, society and the environment can end up bearing those additional costs.

A common example of a Pigovian-style tax is a tax on pollution. Pollution from a factory creates a negative externality because third parties bear part of the cost of production. This cost might manifest itself through contaminated property, destroyed wetlands and streams, or health risks. The polluter only takes into consideration the private costs, not the external costs.

Once Pigou factored in external costs to society, the economy suffered deadweight loss from excess pollution beyond the "socially optimal" level. Pigou believed that state intervention should correct negative externalities, which he considered a market failure. He suggested that this be accomplished through taxation.

Advantages and Disadvantages of a Pigovian Tax

Advantages

Some economists favor Pigovian taxes because they tend to correct for negative externalities, which can be a burden on the public. For example, air pollution from a factory may result in health issues like lung cancer among the population. According to the theory, if the polluter were forced to pay a tax, that could not only help offset the economic cost of such illnesses but discourage the factory from polluting so much in the first place. This means that Pigovian taxes benefit society and tend to improve social welfare, so long as they are properly applied.

Disadvantages

Pigou's externality theories were dominant in mainstream economics for 40 years but lost favor after Nobel Prize-winner Ronald Coase demonstrated that Pigou's examination and solution were often wrong, for at least three separate reasons:

  1. Negative externalities did not necessarily lead to an inefficient result.
  2. Even if they were inefficient, Pigovian taxes did not tend to lead to an efficient result.
  3. The critical element is transaction cost theory, not externality theory.

Pigovian taxes also encounter what Austrian economist Ludwig von Mises first described as "calculation and knowledge problems." A government cannot impose the correct Pigovian tax without knowing in advance what the most efficient outcome is. This would require knowing the precise amount of the externality cost imposed by the producer, as well as the correct price and output for the specific market. If lawmakers overestimate the external costs involved, Pigovian taxes can cause more harm than good, critics maintain.

Pros
  • Reduce negative externalities

  • Promote social welfare

  • Can generate tax revenue

Cons
  • Pigovian taxes are difficult to calculate properly

  • Imposing the wrong tax would be inefficient and costly

  • Taxes like gas taxes can hit low-income consumers hardest

Examples of a Pigovian Tax

Despite any counterarguments toward Pigou's theories, Pigovian taxes are prevalent in society today. One of the most widespread Pigovian taxes is the carbon emissions tax. Some governments impose such taxes on any company that burns fossil fuels. When burned, fossil fuels emit greenhouse gases, which cause global warming, damaging the planet in a multitude of ways.

The carbon tax is intended to factor in the real cost of burning fossil fuels, which is paid by society. The end role of the carbon tax is to ensure that the producers of the emissions are the ones incurring this external cost.

Another Pigovian tax, common in Europe, is a tax on plastic bags, and sometimes even paper bags. This encourages consumers to bring their own reusable bags from home to discourage the use of plastic and paper. Plastic is a byproduct of burning fossil fuels and results in damage to marine life, while paper bags can exacerbate deforestation. By charging even a small amount, like a few cents per bag, the tax discourages their production.

Taxes on "sin" items like alcohol and cigarettes can also be construed as Pigovian taxes. This is because they discourage behavior that can not only harm the individual user but also have damaging effects on others. Second-hand smoke is an obvious example, but so too is the financial burden on the healthcare system from smokers who become ill with cancer or emphysema. Alcohol is responsible for drunk driving accidents, including injuries and deaths among innocent others.

All of the above examples cite negative externalities, where the price of a product does not take into consideration the cost to society. The respective taxes are meant to redistribute those costs back to the producer (or product user) that caused the negative externality.

Note

Gasoline taxes can be considered Pigovian taxes since they discourage unnecessary driving, and proceeds are used to build, repair, and upgrade transportation infrastructure that benefits society. Each state has its own gas tax in the U.S., and the federal government imposes an additional gas tax of 18.4 cents per gallon for unleaded gasoline (24.4 cents for diesel).

What Is a Negative Externality?

In economics, a negative externality is a byproduct produced by some individual, business, or industry that has a negative impact on society, but where the entity that created this byproduct does not pay for it. Instead, society pays the price. Examples include air and noise pollution, toxic runoff, and the inadvertent killing of pollinators through pesticides, among others.

What Is the Difference Between a Pigovian Tax and a Sin Tax?

Pigovian taxes and sin taxes are quite similar and a specific levy may satisfy both definitions. The key difference is that a Pigovian tax seeks primarily to minimize negative externalities (i.e., harms to others or society as a whole), while sin taxes typically seek to reduce negative internalities (i.e., harms to oneself). In the case of cigarettes and alcohol, for example, there are both potential negative internalities and externalities.

How Do You Calculate a Pigovian Tax?

Calculating a Pigovian tax is notoriously difficult to get right. In theory, the amount of the tax should be exactly equal to the net cost of the externality it seeks to remedy. Thus, the tax represents the difference between the social cost and the marginal private cost at a given level of production.

The Bottom Line

While few consumers, except for professional economists, may recognize the name, Pigovian taxes are in wide use today. There are, however, some doubts about their effectiveness.

Article Sources
Investopedia requires writers to use primary sources to support their work. These include white papers, government data, original reporting, and interviews with industry experts. We also reference original research from other reputable publishers where appropriate. You can learn more about the standards we follow in producing accurate, unbiased content in our editorial policy.
  1. The History of Economic Thought. "Arthur Cecil Pigou, 1877-1959."

  2. U.S. Energy Information Administration. "How Much Tax Do We Pay on a Gallon of Gasoline and on a Gallon of Diesel Fuel?"

  3. Core-Econ.org. "Leibniz 12.3.1: Pigouvian Taxes."

Open a New Bank Account
×
The offers that appear in this table are from partnerships from which Investopedia receives compensation. This compensation may impact how and where listings appear. Investopedia does not include all offers available in the marketplace.
Sponsor
Name
Description